Enforcement Institutions and Economic Development

Markets rest on institutions that ensure individuals can commit to keep their contractual obligations. The literature has focused both on formal contract-enforcing institutions, where contracts can be enforced by a third party such as a court of law, and informal institutions where the parties enforce an informal contract themselves. Self-enforcing agreements are particularly important in international trade because the jurisdictions of courts of law often do not extend beyond national borders, particularly at a relatively early stage of economic development. One branch of the literature explores whether liberal political institutions such as limited government and the rule of law, which are necessary for a well functioning court system, lead to the expansion of markets or vice versa. A particular focus of attention in this literature is the endogenous emergence of market supporting institutions in the early history of international trade. This is an important question to the extent that development failure is caused by an absence of this type of institution. A second branch of the literature looks at what types of institutions are required to support the supply of high quality goods and services. The concern here rests on recognition that developing countries often lack well functioning formal contract-enforcement institutions. The question becomes one of whether informal institutions such as social networks that do exist in developing countries can support the delivery of high quality (or efficient) outcomes in the absence of formal institutions. While intuition might suggest that formal and informal institutions serve as substitutes, a key insight from this literature is that formal and informal institutions can in fact complement one another.

Battigalli, P. and G. Maggi, (2002); “Rigidity, Discretion, and the Cost of Writing Contracts.” American Economic Review, 92: 798–817. [Earlier version]

Battigalli, P. and G. Maggi, (2008); “Costly Contracting in a Long-Term RelationshipRAND Journal of Economics, 39(2): 352–377. [Earlier version]

Besley, T.J, M. Ghatak, and K. Burchardi (2012) “Incentives and the de Soto EffectQuarterly Journal of Economics, 127(1): 237-282.

Dhillon, A. and J. Rigolini (2011); “Development and the Interaction of Enforcement Institutions.Journal of Public Economics, 95: 79-87.

Dixit, A. (2003); “On Modes of Economic Governance.” Econometrica, 71(2): 449-481. [Earlier version]

Grief, A. (1993); “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders’ Coalition.American Economic Review, 83(3): 525-548.

Greif, A. (2004); “Commitment, Coercion and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange.” Published in C. Menary and M.M. Shirley (eds) Handbook for New Institutional Economics, Norwell, MA, Kluwer Academic Publications, 727-786.

Greif, A., P. Milgrom and B.R Weingast (1994); “Coordination, Commitment and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild.Journal of Political Economy, 102(4): 745-776.

MacLeod, B. (2007); “Reputations, Relationships and Contract Enforcement.Journal of Economic Literature, 45(3): 597-630. [Earlier version]

Milgrom, P., D.C. North, B.R. Weingast, (1990); “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Medieval Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs.” Economics and Politics, 1: 1-23.