Job Opportunity: Tenure-Track Assistant Professor, International Macroeconomics, University of San Francisco, CA

The Department of Economics at the University of San Francisco invites applications for a tenure-track position in the field of International/Open Economy Macroeconomics, broadly defined, at the Assistant Professor level beginning in August 2016, pending approval and funding. Preference is for a supplementary field and/or applied research in Economic History, Trade, Econometrics, Financial Economics, or Political Economy. The USF Economics Department offers an undergraduate Economics major, an MA in Economics, and an MS in International & Development Economics (IDEC).

12/1/2015
Available immediately

Link to this opportunity

Workshop: Networks, Complexity, and Economic Development – Centre for Economic and Regional Studies, Hungarian Academy of Sciences (MTA KRTK) Budapest, Hungary

The Economics of Networks Research Unit at Centre for Economic and Regional Studies of Hungarian Academy of Sciences is pleased to announce the workshop on “Networks, Complexity, and Economic Development”.

Networks are one of the central challenges of today’s science and the analysis of large-scale social networks integrates scholars from a wide variety of sciences in understanding complex social and economic phenomena. The workshop aims to establish a platform for interdisciplinary discussions focusing on economic development.

Invited talks

Cesar A. Hidalgo, MIT

“Why Information Grows: The Evolution of Order, from Atoms to Economies”

“The shapes of the city: new computational methods to understand urban perception, gentrification, and economic agglomerations at the neighborhood scale” (with Edward Glaeser)

 Ádám Szeidl, CEU and CEPR

“Interfirm Relationships and Business Performance” (with Jing Cai)

Balázs Vedres, CEU

“Fragility in European economic integration: Lessons from the network of inter-industries flow data”

 

Call

We invite PhD students, and early career researchers from economics, sociology, geography, computational social science, and network science to present a paper and discuss future research. Interested fellows from other fields might submit an abstract as well. Papers that address the following topics are particularly (but not exclusively) welcome:

  • Economics of social networks
  • Dynamics of large scale economic networks
  • Innovation and spreading
  • Human mobility and networks
  • Networks of international trade
  • Proximity and economic development
  • Social networks and performance

The workshop is open to the public; however, due to place limitations, registration is required.

 

Dates

  • Abstract submission: 19 October 2015
  • Notification of acceptance: 26 October 2015
  • Registration: 16 November 2015
  • Workshop: 30 November – 1 December 2015

Workshop website

Job Opportunity: Full Professor or Assistant Professor (tenure track) in Development Economics – HEC Lausanne

The starting date is August 1st, 2016, or upon mutual agreement.

The successful candidate will be a member of the Department of Economics at HEC Lausanne. Our department aims at hiring first-rate international researchers.

Applicants must hold a PhD in economics with a specialization in Development Economics (both Micro or Macro). Preference will be given to candidates with a confirmed capacity to publish in leading academic journals and with solid experience in university-level teaching. The rank of appointment will be determined by the candidate’s publication record and academic experience.

The successful candidate will be expected to be able to teach in French after two years. A detailed job description and the electronic application form are available at: www.hec.unil.ch.

Applications must be submitted online using the above link until December 1st, 2015 (11.59 pm local time). Please fill in the electronic application form, including the names and addresses of three references maximum, and upload your curriculum vitae, a cover letter and samples of your scholarly work via the same site. Candidates should indicate in their cover letter whether they will be available for interviews at the January 2016 AEA Meeting in San Francisco.

Additional information can be obtained from Professor Olivier Cadot () or Professor Dominic Rohner ().

Seeking to promote a balanced representation of men and women among its academic staff, the University encourages women to apply.

Job Opportunity: Assistant, Associate or Full Professor – Macroeconomics and International Economics University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign

University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign

Urbana, IL

The Department of Economics invites applications for a full-time tenure/tenure track position in the field of Macroeconomics and International Economics. The Department offers a Ph.D. degree, a professional Master’s degree (MSPE), and an undergraduate degree (BA). For information about the Department, see www.economics.illinois.edu. Successful candidates are expected to teach effectively at both the undergraduate and graduate levels, establish and maintain an active and independent research program, and provide service to the department, the university and the profession. The salary will be commensurate with the research record and other accomplishments. The target starting date is August 16, 2016.

Closing date: December 1, 2015

Link to this opportunity

Job Opportunity: Integration and Trade Economist Senior

The Inter-American Development Bank, the largest and leading source of financing for regional development in Latin America and the Caribbean, is seeking highly qualified Economists to work in the Integration and Trade Sector. Candidates must have proven research experience in specialized trade and economic integration issues, in particular in areas such as trade-related labor market dynamics, trade finance, transport costs and trade facilitation; foreign investment and financial market integration. He/she will be part of a team with a mission to influence regional policies and IDB loan and technical assistance programs in these areas. 

Link to this opportunity

Call for Papers: Royal Economic Society Conference 2016

University of Sussex, 21 to 23 March 2016

Submissions are invited for the 2016 Annual Conference of the Royal Economic Society, taking place from Monday 21 March to Wednesday 23 March 2016 at the University of Sussex, Brighton.

Submissions of papers and special sessions are invited from academic, government and business economists in any field of economics and econometrics. The deadlines for submissions are as follows:

  • Deadline for the submission of papers: 11 October 2015.  This must be done via the link available on the conference webpage.
  • Deadline for the submission of special session proposals: 1 November 2015.  These should be sent by email to the Programme Chair () and should include a short description of the intended session along with the proposed list of contributors (typically three/four, perhaps including the proposer) and indicative paper titles.
  • Notification of acceptance will be by the end of December 2015, while online registration opens from January 2016.

The keynotes lectures will be given by:

  • Esther Duflo (MIT) – Economic Journal Lecture
  • Kristin Forbes (MIT and MPC) – Hahn Lecture
  • Susanne Schennach (Brown) – Sargan Lecture

In addition to the main conference agenda, there will be a drinks reception on Monday 21 March at the Brighton Museum & Art Gallery, set in the beautiful Pavilion Gardens, with the opportunity for delegates to tour the Royal Pavilion. The conference Gala Dinner will take place at Brighton’s iconic seafront Grand Hotel onTuesday 22 March.

Further information about the conference, including details of financial assistance for PhD students, is available via the conference webpage: http://www.res.org.uk/view/0/2016conference_home.html

Authors of papers accepted for presentation at the 2016 RES conference will be entitled to submit their papers for possible publication in the associated conference issue of the Economic Journal.

Please feel free to contact the Programme Chair (Richard Dickens) or Deputy Programme Chair (Holger Breinlich) if you have questions about this Call, or the Local Organiser (Dimitra Petropoulou) with wider questions about the conference.

New Working Papers – August 2015

The following working papers have recently been added to our working papers page.

Dreher, Axel, Andreas Fuchs, Roland Hodler, Bradley C. Parks, Paul A. Raschky and Michael J. Tierney (2015) “Aid on Demand: African Leaders and the Geography of China’s Foreign Assistance”  

Hessami, Zohal, Claudio Thum and Silke Uebelmesser (2012) “A Political Economy Explanation for In‐kind Redistribution: The Interplay of Corruption and Democracy

Krishna, Kala (2014)“Wheat or Strawberries? Intermediated Trade with Limited Contracting

Krishna, Kala, Sergey Lychagin and Veronica Frisancho Robles (2015) “Retaking in High Stakes Exams: Is Less More?

Lake, James (2015) “Why don’t more countries form Customs Unions instead of Free Trade Agreements? The role of flexibility

Lake, James and Maia Linask (2015) “Domestic political competition and pro-cyclical import protection

Magda, Iga , David Marsden and Simone Moriconi (2015) Lower coverage but stronger unions? Institutional changes and union wage premia in central Europe

8th FIW Research Conference ‘International Economics’

December 3-4, 2015 – WIFO (Austrian Institute of Economic Research)

Venue: WIFO (Austrian Institute of Economic Research)Arsenal, Object 20, 1030 Vienna

Keynote Lecture: Prof. Dr. Franz Hubert (Humboldt-Unviversity Berlin)

The Research Centre International Economics – FIW announces its 8th Research Conference that is jointly organized with the Institute for East and Southeast European Studies (IOS) Regensburg, the Ifo Institute, the University of Ljubljana and the Hungarian Academy of Sciences (MTA KRTK) and invites the submission of papers to be presented at the conference. The main objective of the conference is to provide a platform for economists working in the field of ‘International Economics’ in Austria and its neighbouring countries to present recent research.

Papers from Ph.D. students, post-graduate students, young faculty members and young researchers in similar positions are particularly welcome as the conference aims to support and encourage young economists by providing an opportunity to present their work. Participants will have the opportunity to interact in a dynamic and open atmosphere and to discuss their papers/research ideas with experts in the field of ‘International Economics’.

TOPICS COVERED

The broad topic of the conference is ‘International Economics’. This includes, inter alia, the areas of Trade, International Factor Movements, Economic Integration, Trade Policy, International Trade Organizations, Economic Growth of Open Economies, Multinational Firms, International Macroeconomics and other related fields.

Deadline for Submission: September 14, 2015

Conference Website

ZEW Workshop on the Development and Consequences of Atypical Employment

Atypical employment has been of increasing importance in most developed countries. It comprises employment types such as fixed-term contracts, part-time jobs and marginal employment, as well as contract work and temporary agency work, which play a decisive role in the institutional setting of modern labour markets. It has been argued that atypical employment can be beneficial in creating more flexibility for firms and in helping to overcome crises without massive employment losses. Little is known, however, about the consequences of atypical employment on the individual level. On the one hand, concerns have recently been growing that atypical employment positions are only second-best options for workers, compared to regular employment. Atypical positions are associated with detrimental effects on wage growth, on employment prospects and on individual well-being in terms of satisfaction and health. On the other hand, the provision of atypical employment positions might be a response to the demand for flexible work arrangements of specific types of workers in dynamic labour markets. Empirical and theoretical work on the development and consequences of atypical employment can therefore provide valuable evidence for policy-makers regarding the regulation of labour market institutions.

The aim of the workshop is to bring together international researchers in order to present and discuss recent empirical and theoretical contributions regarding the development and consequences of atypical employment.

Topics of interest include (but are not limited to):

  • Trends in atypical employment across different types of worker and countries
  • Quality of atypical employment
  • Dynamic employment and wage effects
  • State dependence in the low-wage sector related to atypical employment
  • Self-employment as an atypical employment type
  • Life-cycle effects of atypical employment
  • Individual well-being and atypical employment
  • Atypical employment induced by new technologies
  • Labour supply and hours constraints
  • Atypical employment in the context of household and fertility decisions
  • Investigation of the role of firms using linked employer-employee data
  • Effects of policy reforms on the consequences of atypical employment
  • Atypical employment as a stepping stone to regular employment
  • Institutional relationship between unions, minimum wages and atypical employment
  • Relationship between unemployment and atypical employment in a job search context

The deadline for submission of full papers or extended abstracts is September 27 2015.

Workshop dates: December 2-3 2015

Location of the workshop: ZEW, L 7,1 D-68161 Mannheim

Workshop Website

Beyond Gravity: The Composition of Multilateral Trade

By Ahmad Lashkaripour (Indiana University Bloomington)

What type of goods does the US export to Canada? What type of goods does it export to New Zealand? Guided by a standard gravity model we know very well that the US exports more (in value terms) to Canada than New Zealand. However, gravity models tell us little about the composition of US exports across various destinations. Standard gravity models focus on the intensive margin of trade. Tracking the evolution of trade patterns and trade theory over time explains why the gravity models were constructed this way, and why it’s time to move forward.

Trade theory, before the 1980s, had a sharp focus: describing the commodity composition of trade. Classical theories described the exchange of dissimilar goods between dissimilar countries in a bilateral world. In a classical framework, the labor abundant country would export the labor-intensive good, whereas the capital abundant country would export the capital-intensive good. In the early 1980s, evidence pointed to a different –non-classical– type of trade: exchange of similar goods between similar countries. To account for this type of trade, trade theory experienced a shift in paradigm, and gravity models were born. Gravity models describe the volume of trade in a multilateral world, where both similar and dissimilar countries engage in two-way trade. In contrast to classical models, gravity models are tractable and easy to estimate in a general equilibrium multi-country setting. Tractability, however, comes at a cost. Gravity models overlook the composition margin, and do not deliver detailed predictions about what type of goods countries trade.

Two recent developments, however, point to the increasing importance of the composition margin. First, poor and remote countries have become increasingly engaged in global trade (in 2006, for the first time, the US did more trade with developing countries than with other developed nations). Second, micro-level evidence indicates that both geography (remoteness) and per capita income have systematic effects on the composition of trade. This evidence is exemplified by three basic facts:

  1. Geography systematically affects the price-composition of exports (faraway countries exchange higher price, higher quality, goods)
  1. Per capita income increases the price-composition of exports (within narrowly defined categories, rich countries export higher price, higher quality goods)
  1. Trade-to-GDP increases systematically with per capita income (rich countries import and export goods that are more tradable).

These facts are beyond the scope of both classical and gravity models. In recent years much progress has been made in explaining these facts individually.[i] Nevertheless, there remains a void. First, we do not have a unified theory that accounts for the effect of both geography and per capita income — existing theories usually confront one aspect of the data in isolation, and overlook the others. Second, to address the composition margin, existing theories generally rely on non-homothetic preferences or non-iceberg trade costs. This involves sacrificing tractability, and tractability has been a major force behind the success of gravity models.

In Lashkaripour (2015a), I confront this void. I argue that a simple extension to the theory of comparative advantage could explain both the effect of geography and the effect of per capita income on the composition of trade.[ii] Building on this idea, I develop a unified model that fully describes both the volume and the composition of trade in a multi-lateral world. Similar to standard gravity models, the unified model adopts homothetic preferences and iceberg trade costs, making it tractable and straightforward to estimate. The main insight of the paper, however, concerns the welfare gains from trade. Estimating the model reveals that the composition margin has profound effects on the gains from trade. Specifically, embedding systematic specialization into a gravity model (to account for composition) more than triples the gains from trade. Furthermore, the gains from trade systematically favor poor and remote nations. This outcome is remarkable, given that incorporating other margins such as firm heterogeneity seem to contribute minimally to the gains from trade (Arkolakis et al. (2011)).

Currently, we are equipped with a rich set of theories that shed light on the composition of trade. More importantly, depending on which theory we believe, the composition margin has deep impacts on the gains from global integration. The next major step is evaluating these theories with micro-level data. Caron et al. (2014), among others, have made notable progress on this front.[iii] Further progress in this direction would allow us to better understand the aggregate effects of global integration, especially on poor and remote nations.

References

Arkolakis, C., A. Costinot, and A. Rodriguez (2012). Clare, 2012, new trade models, same old gains. American Economic Review 102(1), 94.

Baldwin, R. and J. Harrigan (2011). Zeros, quality, and space: Trade theory and trade evidence. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 3(2), 60–88.

Caron, J., T. Fally, and J. R. Markusen (2014). International trade puzzles: A solution linking production and preferences. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(3), 1501–1552.

Dingel, J. I. (2014). The determinants of quality specialization. Technical report, WTO Staff Working Paper.

Eaton, J. and S. Kortum (2002). Technology, geography, and trade. Econometrica 70(5), 1741–1779.

Fajgelbaum, P., G. M. Grossman, and E. Helpman (2011). Income distribution. Product Quality, and International Trade, Journal of Political Economy 118(4), 721.

Fieler, A. C. (2011). Nonhomotheticity and bilateral trade: evidence and a quantitative explanation. Econometrica 79(4), 1069–1101.

Hummels, D. and A. Skiba (2004). Shipping the good apples out? an empirical confirmation of the Alchian-Allen conjecture. Journal of Political Economy 112(6).

Lashkaripour, A. (2015a). The composition of trade in a multilateral world. Technical report, Center for Applied Economics and Policy Research, Economics Department, Indiana University Bloomington.

Lashkaripour, A. (2015b). Worth its weight in gold: Product weight, international shipping, and patterns of trade.

Melitz, M. (2003). The impact of trade on aggregate industry productivity and intra-industry reallocations. Econometrica 71(6), 1695–1725.

 

[i]To explain the effect of per capita income on the composition margin, many studies have embedded non-homotheticity into standard gravity models. Fieler (2011), for example, embeds non-homthetic preferences into an Eaton-Kortum model.  She assumes that rich countries consume relatively more of goods, which are more technologically differentiated. Such goods are subject to lower trade elasticities and are more tradable. This entails that rich countries import a higher share of their GDP. Another example is Fajgelbaum et al. (2011), who apply non-homotheticity to a Krugman model. In their framework the home market effect induces firms in rich countries to specialize in high-quality goods. As a result, rich countries become net exporters of high-price, high quality products.

To account for the effect of geography on the composition of trade, most studies abstract from the standard iceberg cost assumption, and assume that trade costs are additive. This approach builds on the Alchian-Allen conjecture, and is exemplified in Hummels and Skiba (2004). Baldwin and Harrigan (2011) offer an alternative theory that reconciles the effect of geography (on composition) with iceberg trade costs. Building on Melitz (2003), they develop a quality-sorting framework where high-quality firms are the most competitive and sort into the toughest, most remote markets.

[ii] I relax a commonly used “gravity” assumption that does not align with micro-level evidence. Standard gravity models assume that all goods offer the same scope for product differentiation, whereas I allow for two types of goods: a highly differentiated type and a less differentiated type. By definition, demand for the highly differentiated type is quality-intensive, whereas demand for the less differentiated type is quantity-intensive. In equilibrium, quality abundant (high-wage) and remote countries have comparative advantage in the highly differentiated type. Labor abundant (low-wage) countries, on the other hand, have comparative advantage in the less differentiated type. This leads to systematic international specialization in production. Production specialization combined with the fact that (in equilibrium) the highly differentiated type exhibits a higher markup and is more tradable, explain the composition of multi-lateral trade.

[iii]Caron et al. (2014) show that income-elastic goods are more skill-intensive. Their results imply that non-homotheticity is an important factor in explaining puzzles relating to composition. Dingel (2015) utilizes firm-level data to discriminate between two theories that explain the higher price-mix of exports from rich countries. He shows that the Home-market effect is as important as comparative advantage in explaining this pattern. In Lashkaripour (2015b), I use product level data to analyze the effect of geography on the price composition of exports. Estimation results indicate that markups are the main driver of the observed patterns.